The Sick-Sicker model

In this case-study, we perform a cost-effectiveness analysis (CEA) using a previously published 4-state model called the Sick-Sicker model (E. A. Enns et al. 2015). In the Sick-Sicker model, a hypothetical disease affects individuals with an average age of 25 years and results in increased mortality, increased treatment costs and reduced quality of life (QoL). We simulate this hypothetical cohort of 25-year-old individuals over a lifetime (i.e., reaching an age of 100 years old) using 75 annual cycles, represented with n_t. The cohort starts in the “Healthy” health state (denoted “H”). Healthy individuals are at risk of developing the illness, at which point they would transition to the first stage of the disease (the “Sick” health state, denoted “S1”). Sick individuals are at risk of further progressing to a more severe stage (the “Sicker” health state, denoted “S2”), which is a constant probability in this case-study. There is a chance that individuals in the Sick state eventually recover and return back to the Healthy state. However, once an individual reaches the Sicker state, they cannot recover; that is, the probability of transitioning to the Sick or Healthy states from the Sicker state is zero. Individuals in the Healthy state face background mortality that is age-specific (i.e., time-dependent). Sick and Sicker individuals face an increased mortality expressed as a hazard rate ratio (HR) of 3 and 10, respectively, on the background mortality rate. Sick and Sicker individuals also experience increased health care costs and reduced QoL compared to healthy individuals. Once simulated individuals die, they transition to the “Dead” state (denoted “D”), where they remain. Figure shows the state-transition diagram of the Sick-Sicker model. The evolution of the cohort is simulated in one-year discrete-time cycles. Both costs and quality-adjusted life years (QALYs) are discounted at an annual rate of 0.03%.

State-transition diagram of the Sick-Sicker model. Healthy individuals can get Sick, die or stay healthy. Sick individuals can recover, transitioning back to healthy, can die, or stay sick. Once individuals are Sicker, they stay Sicker until they die.

State-transition diagram of the Sick-Sicker model. Healthy individuals can get Sick, die or stay healthy. Sick individuals can recover, transitioning back to healthy, can die, or stay sick. Once individuals are Sicker, they stay Sicker until they die.

Two alternative strategies exist for this hypothetical disease: a no-treatment and a treatment strategy. Under the treatment strategy, Sick and Sicker individuals receive treatment and continue doing so until they recover or die. The cost of the treatment is additional to the cost of being Sick or Sicker for one year. The treatment improves QoL for those individuals who are Sick but has no effect on the QoL of those who are sicker. To evaluate these two alternative strategies, we perform a CEA.

We assume that most of the parameters of the Sick-Sicker model and their uncertainty have been previously estimated and are known to the analyst. However, while we can identify those who are afflicted with the illness through obvious symptoms, we can not easily distinguish those in the Sick state from the those in the Sicker state. Thus, we can not directly estimate state-specific mortality hazard rate ratios, nor do we know the transition probability of progressing from Sick to Sicker. Therefore, we calibrate the model to different epidemiological data. We internally validated the calibrated model by comparing the predicted outputs from the model evaluated at the calibrated parameters against the calibration targets (Eddy et al. 2012, Goldhaber-Fiebert, Stout, and Goldie (2010)).

As part of the CEA, we conducted different deterministic sensitivity analysis (SA), including one-way and two-way SA, and tornado plots. To quantify the effect of parameter uncertainty on decision uncertainty, we conducted a probabilistic sensitivity analysis (PSA) and reported our uncertainty analysis results with a cost-effectiveness acceptability curve (CEAC), cost-effectiveness acceptability frontier (CEAF) and expected loss curves (ELC) (Alarid-Escudero et al. 2019). We also conducted a value of information (VOI) analysis to determine whether potential future research is needed to reduce parameter uncertainty. All steps of the CEA will be described using the different components of the framework.

References

Alarid-Escudero, F, EA Enns, KM Kuntz, TL Michaud, and H Jalal. 2019. “‘Time Traveling Is Just Too Dangerous’ But Some Methods Are Worth Revisiting: The Advantages of Expected Loss Curves Over Cost-Effectiveness Acceptability Curves and Frontier.” Value in Health 22 (5): 611–18. doi:10.1016/j.jval.2019.02.008.

Eddy, David M., William Hollingworth, J. Jaime Caro, Joel Tsevat, Kathryn M. McDonald, and John B. Wong. 2012. “Model transparency and validation: A report of the ISPOR-SMDM modeling good research practices task force-7.” Medical Decision Making 32 (5): 733–43. doi:10.1177/0272989X12454579.

Enns, E A, L E Cipriano, C T Simons, and C Y Kong. 2015. “Identifying Best-Fitting Inputs in Health-Economic Model Calibration: A Pareto Frontier Approach.” Medical Decision Making 35 (2): 170–82. doi:10.1177/0272989X14528382.

Goldhaber-Fiebert, JD, NK Stout, and SJ Goldie. 2010. “Empirically evaluating decision-analytic models.” Value in Health 13 (5): 667–74. doi:10.1111/j.1524-4733.2010.00698.x.